In mathematics, a vector measure is a function defined on a family of sets and taking vector space values satisfying certain properties. It is a generalization of the concept of finite measure, which takes nonnegative real number values only.
A vector measure is called countably additive if for any sequence of disjoint sets in such that their union is in it holds that with the series on the right-hand side convergent in the norm of the Banach space
It can be proved that an additive vector measure is countably additive if and only if for any sequence as above one has
where is the norm on
Countably additive vector measures defined on are more general than finite measures, finite , and , which are countably additive functions taking values respectively on the real interval the set of , and the set of .
Both of these statements follow quite easily from the criterion () stated above.
The variation of is a finitely additive function taking values in It holds that for any in If is finite, the measure is said to be of bounded variation. One can prove that if is a vector measure of bounded variation, then is countably additive if and only if is countably additive.
Vind's article was noted by with this comment:
The concept of a convex set (i.e., a set containing the segment connecting any two of its points) had repeatedly been placed at the center of economic theory before 1964. It appeared in a new light with the introduction of integration theory in the study of economic competition: If one associates with every agent of an economy an arbitrary set in the commodity space and if one averages those individual sets over a collection of insignificant agents, then the resulting set is necessarily convex. Debreu But explanations of the ... functions of prices ... can be made to rest on the convexity of sets derived by that averaging process. Convexity in the commodity space obtained by aggregation over a collection of insignificant agents is an insight that economic theory owes ... to integration theory. ''Italics
in ("bang–bang") control theory, and in statistical theory. Lyapunov's theorem has been proved by using the Shapley–Folkman lemma, which has been viewed as a discretization analogue of Lyapunov's theorem.Page 210:
|
|