Product Code Database
Example Keywords: paint -hat $88
   » » Wiki: Money
Tag Wiki 'Money'.
Tag

Money is any item or verifiable record that is generally accepted as for goods and services and repayment of , such as , in a particular country or socio-economic context.

(2025). 9780321421777, Addison Wesley.
What Is Money? By John N. Smithin. Retrieved July-17-09. The primary functions which distinguish money are: medium of exchange, a unit of account, a store of value and sometimes, a standard of deferred payment.

Money was historically an emergent market phenomenon that possessed intrinsic value as a ; nearly all contemporary money systems are based on unbacked without . Its value is consequently derived by social convention, having been declared by a or regulatory entity to be ; that is, it must be accepted as a form of payment within the boundaries of the country, for "all debts, public and private", in the case of the United States dollar.

The of a country comprises all currency in circulation ( and currently issued) and, depending on the particular definition used, one or more types of (the balances held in checking accounts, , and other types of ). Bank money, whose value exists on the books of financial institutions and can be converted into physical notes or used for , forms by far the largest part of in developed countries.


Etymology
The word money derives from the Latin word moneta with the meaning "coin" via French monnaie. The Latin word is believed to originate from a temple of Juno, on , one of Rome's seven hills. In the ancient world, Juno was often associated with money. The temple of at Rome was the place where the mint of Ancient Rome was located.D'Eprio, Peter & Pinkowish, Mary Desmond (1998). What Are the Seven Wonders of the World? First Anchor Books, p. 192. The name "Juno" may have derived from the Etruscan goddess Uni and "Moneta" either from the Latin word "monere" (remind, warn, or instruct) or the Greek word "moneres" (alone, unique).

In the Western world, a prevalent term for coin-money has been , stemming from Latin in specie, meaning "in kind".


History
The use of -like methods may date back to at least 100,000 years ago, though there is no evidence of a society or economy that relied primarily on barter.. The Gift: The Form and Reason for Exchange in Archaic Societies. pp. 36–37. Instead, non-monetary societies operated largely along the principles of and .David Graeber: Debt: The First 5000 Years, Melville 2011. Cf. review When barter did in fact occur, it was usually between either complete strangers or potential enemies.
(2025). 9780312240455, Palgrave Macmillan. .

Many cultures around the world eventually developed the use of . The Mesopotamian was a unit of weight, and relied on the mass of something like 160 grains of .Kramer, History Begins at Sumer, pp. 52–55. The first usage of the term came from circa 3000 BC. Societies in the Americas, Asia, Africa and Australia used —often, the shells of the ( Cypraea moneta L. or C. annulus L.). According to , the were the first people to introduce the use of and .Herodotus. Histories, I, 94 It is thought by modern scholars that these first stamped were minted around 650 to 600 BC.

The system of eventually evolved into a system of representative money. This occurred because gold and silver merchants or banks would issue receipts to their depositors, redeemable for the deposited. Eventually, these receipts became generally accepted as a means of payment and were used as money. Paper money or were first used in China during the . These banknotes, known as "jiaozi", evolved from that had been used since the 7th century. However, they did not displace commodity money and were used alongside coins. In the 13th century, paper money became known in Europe through the accounts of travellers, such as and William of Rubruck.

(2025). 9781436306942
Marco Polo's account of paper money during the is the subject of a chapter of his book, The Travels of Marco Polo, titled "." Banknotes were first issued in Europe by in 1661 and were again also used alongside coins. The , a where the medium of exchange are paper notes that are convertible into pre-set, fixed quantities of gold, replaced the use of gold coins as currency in the 17th–19th centuries in Europe. These gold standard notes were made , and redemption into gold coins was discouraged. By the beginning of the 20th century, almost all countries had adopted the gold standard, backing their legal tender notes with fixed amounts of gold.

After World War II and the Bretton Woods Conference, most countries adopted fiat currencies that were fixed to the U.S. dollar. The U.S. dollar was in turn fixed to gold. In 1971 the U.S. government suspended the convertibility of the dollar to gold. After this many countries de-pegged their currencies from the U.S. dollar, and most of the world's currencies became unbacked by anything except the governments' fiat of legal tender and the ability to convert the money into goods via payment. According to proponents of modern money theory, fiat money is also backed by taxes. By imposing taxes, states create demand for the currency they issue.

(2025). 9780230368897, Palgrave Macmillan.


Functions
In Money and the Mechanism of Exchange (1875), William Stanley Jevons famously analyzed money in terms of four functions: a medium of exchange, a common measure of value (or unit of account), a standard of value (or standard of deferred payment), and a store of value. By 1919, Jevons's four functions of money were summarized in the :
Money's a matter of functions four,
A Medium, a Measure, a Standard, a Store.

This couplet would later become widely popular in macroeconomics textbooks. Most modern textbooks now list only three functions, that of medium of exchange, unit of account, and store of value, not considering a standard of deferred payment as a distinguished function, but rather subsuming it in the others.

(2025). 9780716762133, Worth Publishers.
Krugman, Paul & Wells, Robin, Economics, Worth Publishers, New York (2006)
(2025). 9780201327892, Pearson.

There have been many historical disputes regarding the combination of money's functions, some arguing that they need more separation and that a single unit is insufficient to deal with them all. One of these arguments is that the role of money as a medium of exchange conflicts with its role as a store of value: its role as a store of value requires holding it without spending, whereas its role as a medium of exchange requires it to circulate.T.H. Greco. Money: Understanding and Creating Alternatives to Legal Tender, White River Junction, Vt: Chelsea Green Publishing (2001). Others argue that storing of value is just deferral of the exchange, but does not diminish the fact that money is a medium of exchange that can be transported both across space and time. The term "financial capital" is a more general and inclusive term for all liquid instruments, whether or not they are a uniformly recognized tender.


Medium of exchange
When money is used to intermediate the exchange of goods and services, it is performing a function as a medium of exchange. It thereby avoids the inefficiencies of a barter system, such as the inability to permanently ensure "coincidence of wants". For example, between two parties in a barter system, one party may not have or make the item that the other wants, indicating the non-existence of the coincidence of wants. Having a medium of exchange can alleviate this issue because the former can have the freedom to spend time on other items, instead of being burdened to only serve the needs of the latter. Meanwhile, the latter can use the medium of exchange to seek for a party that can provide them with the item they want.


Measure of value
A unit of account (in economics) is a standard numerical monetary unit of measurement of the market value of goods, services, and other transactions. Also known as a "measure" or "standard" of relative worth and deferred payment, a unit of account is a necessary prerequisite for the formulation of commercial agreements that involve debt.

Money acts as a standard measure and a common denomination of trade. It is thus a basis for quoting and bargaining of prices. It is necessary for developing efficient accounting systems like double-entry bookkeeping.


Standard of deferred payment
While standard of deferred payment is distinguished by some texts, particularly older ones, other texts subsume this under other functions. A "standard of deferred payment" is an accepted way to settle a —a unit in which debts are denominated, and the status of money as , in those jurisdictions which have this concept, states that it may function for the discharge of debts. The standard of deferred payment allows people to buy now pay later. When debts are denominated in money, the real value of debts may change due to inflation and , and for sovereign and international debts via and .


Store of value
To act as a store of value, money must be able to be reliably saved, stored, and retrieved—and be predictably usable as a medium of exchange when it is retrieved. The value of the money must also remain stable over time. Some have argued that inflation, by reducing the value of money, diminishes the ability of the money to function as a store of value.


Properties
The functions of money are that it is a medium of exchange, a unit of account, and a store of value. To fulfill these various functions, money must be:
  • : its individual units must be capable of mutual substitution (i.e., interchangeability).
  • : able to withstand repeated use.
  • Divisible: divisible to small units.
  • Portable: easily carried and transported.
  • Acceptable: most people must accept the money as payment
  • Scarce: its supply in circulation must be limited.


Money supply
In economics, money is any financial instrument that can fulfill the functions of money (detailed above). These financial instruments together are collectively referred to as the of an economy. In other words, the money supply is the number of financial instruments within a specific economy available for purchasing goods or services. Since the money supply consists of various financial instruments (usually currency, demand deposits, and various other types of deposits), the amount of money in an economy is measured by adding together these financial instruments creating a monetary aggregate.

Economists employ different ways to measure the stock of money or money supply, reflected in different types of monetary aggregates, using a categorization system that focuses on the of the financial instrument used as money. The most commonly used monetary aggregates (or types of money) are conventionally designated M1, M2, and M3. These are successively larger aggregate categories: M1 is currency (coins and bills) plus (such as checking accounts); M2 is M1 plus and under $100,000; M3 is M2 plus larger time deposits and similar institutional accounts. M1 includes only the most liquid financial instruments, and M3 relatively illiquid instruments. The precise definition of M1, M2, etc. may be different in different countries.

Another measure of money, M0, is also used. M0 is , or the amount of money actually issued by the of a country. It is measured as currency plus deposits of banks and other institutions at the central bank. M0 is also the only money that can satisfy the reserve requirements of .


Creation of money
In current economic systems, money is created by two procedures:

Legal tender, or narrow money (M0) is the cash created by a Central Bank by minting coins and printing banknotes.

Bank money, or broad money (M1/M2) is the money created by private banks through the recording of loans as deposits of borrowing clients, with partial support indicated by the cash ratio. Currently, bank money is created as electronic money.

Bank money, whose value exists on the books of financial institutions and can be converted into physical notes or used for cashless payment, forms by far the largest part of in developed countries.

(2025). 9781932857269, The Disinformation Company.
Bernstein, Peter, A Primer on Money and Banking, and Gold, Wiley, 2008 edition, pp. 29–39

In most countries, the majority of money is mostly created as M1/M2 by commercial banks making loans. Contrary to some popular misconceptions, banks do not act simply as intermediaries, lending out deposits that savers place with them, and do not depend on central bank money (M0) to create new loans and deposits.


Market liquidity
"Market liquidity" describes how easily an item can be traded for another item, or into the common currency within an economy. Money is the most liquid asset because it is universally recognized and accepted as a common currency. In this way, money gives consumers the to trade goods and services easily without having to barter.

Liquid financial instruments are easily and have low . There should be no (or minimal) spread between the prices to buy and sell the instrument being used as money.


Types

Commodity
Many items have been used as such as naturally scarce , , , beads, etc., as well as many other things that are thought of as having value. Commodity money value comes from the commodity out of which it is made. The commodity itself constitutes the money, and the money is the commodity.Mises, Ludwig von. The Theory of Money and Credit, (Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc., 1981), trans. H. E. Batson. Ch.3 Part One: The Nature of Money, Chapter 3: The Various Kinds of Money, Section 3: Commodity Money, Credit Money, and Fiat Money, Paragraph 25. Examples of commodities that have been used as mediums of exchange include gold, silver, copper, rice, , salt, peppercorns, large stones, decorated belts, shells, alcohol, cigarettes, cannabis, candy, etc. These items were sometimes used in a metric of perceived value in conjunction with one another, in various commodity valuation or economies. The use of commodity money is similar to barter, but a commodity money provides a simple and automatic unit of account for the commodity which is being used as money. Although some such as the are considered , there is no record of their face value on either side of the coin. The rationale for this is that emphasis is laid on their direct link to the prevailing value of their fine gold content. randRefinery.com . Retrieved July-18-09. American Eagles are imprinted with their gold content and legal tender .


Representative
In 1875, the British economist William Stanley Jevons described the money used at the time as "representative money". Representative money is money that consists of , or other physical tokens such as certificates, that can be reliably exchanged for a fixed quantity of a commodity such as gold or silver. The value of representative money stands in direct and fixed relation to the commodity that backs it, while not itself being composed of that commodity.
(1875). 9781596052604, Cosimo.


Fiat
Fiat money or fiat currency is money whose value is not derived from any intrinsic value or guarantee that it can be converted into a valuable commodity (such as gold). Instead, it has value only by government order (fiat). Usually, the government declares the fiat currency (typically notes and coins from a central bank, such as the Federal Reserve System in the U.S.) to be , making it unlawful not to accept the fiat currency as a means of repayment for all debts, public and private.Black, Henry Campbell (1910). A Law Dictionary Containing Definitions Of The Terms And Phrases Of American And English Jurisprudence, Ancient And Modern, p. 494. West Publishing Co. Black's Law Dictionary defines the word "fiat" to mean "a short order or warrant of a Judge or magistrate directing some act to be done; an authority issuing from some competent source for the doing of some legal act"

Some such as the Australian Gold Nugget and American Eagle are legal tender, however, they trade based on the of the metal content as a , rather than their legal tender (which is usually only a small fraction of their bullion value). usmiNT.gov . Retrieved July-18-09. Retrieved July-18-09

Fiat money, if physically represented in the form of currency (paper or coins), can be accidentally damaged or destroyed. However, fiat money has an advantage over representative or commodity money, in that the same laws that created the money can also define rules for its replacement in case of damage or destruction. For example, the U.S. government will replace mutilated Federal Reserve Notes (U.S. fiat money) if at least half of the physical note can be reconstructed, or if it can be otherwise proven to have been destroyed. Shredded & Mutilated: Mutilated Currency, Bureau of Engraving and Printing. Retrieved 2007-05-09. By contrast, commodity money that has been lost or destroyed cannot be recovered.


Demurrage

Coinage
These factors led to the shift of the store of value being the metal itself: at first silver, then both silver and gold, and at one point there was bronze as well. Now we have copper coins and other non-precious metals as coins. Metals were mined, weighed, and stamped into coins. This was to assure the individual taking the coin that he was getting a certain known weight of precious metal. Coins could be counterfeited, but they also created a new unit of account, which helped lead to banking. Archimedes' principle provided the next link: coins could now be easily tested for their weight of the metal, and thus the value of a coin could be determined, even if it had been shaved, debased or otherwise tampered with (see ).

In most major economies using coinage, copper, silver, and gold formed three tiers of coins. Gold coins were used for large purchases, payment of the military, and backing of state activities. Silver coins were used for midsized transactions, and as a unit of account for taxes, dues, contracts, and fealty, while copper coins represented the coinage of common transaction. This system had been used in ancient since the time of the . In Europe, this system worked through the period because there was virtually no new gold, silver, or copper introduced through mining or conquest. Thus the overall ratios of the three coinages remained roughly equivalent.


Paper
In premodern China, the need for credit and for circulating a medium that was less of a burden than exchanging thousands of led to the introduction of . This economic phenomenon was a slow and gradual process that took place from the late (618–907) into the (960–1279). It began as a means for merchants to exchange heavy coinage for of deposit issued as from shops of wholesalers, notes that were valid for temporary use in a small regional territory. In the 10th century, the government began circulating these notes amongst the traders in their salt industry. The Song government granted several shops the sole right to issue banknotes, and in the early 12th century the government finally took over these shops to produce state-issued currency. Yet the banknotes issued were still regionally valid and temporary; it was not until the mid 13th century that a standard and uniform government issue of paper money was made into an acceptable nationwide currency. The already widespread methods of woodblock printing and then 's printing by the 11th century was the impetus for the massive production of paper money in premodern China.

At around the same time in the medieval Islamic world, a vigorous was created during the 7th–12th centuries on the basis of the expanding levels of circulation of a stable high-value currency (the ). Innovations introduced by economists, traders and merchants of the Muslim world include the earliest uses of credit, , , transactional accounts, loaning, , , the transfer of credit and , and banking institutions for loans and .

In Europe, paper money was first introduced in in 1661. Sweden was rich in copper, thus, because of copper's low value, extraordinarily big coins (often weighing several kilograms) had to be made. The advantages of paper currency were numerous: it reduced transport of gold and silver, and thus lowered the risks; it made loaning gold or silver at interest easier since the specie (gold or silver) never left the possession of the lender until someone else redeemed the note; and it allowed for a division of currency into credit and specie backed forms. It enabled the sale of in joint stock companies, and the redemption of those in the paper.

However, these advantages are held within their disadvantages. First, since a note has no intrinsic value, there was nothing to stop issuing authorities from printing more of it than they had specie to back it with. Second, because it increased the money supply, it increased inflationary pressures, a fact observed by in the 18th century. The result is that paper money would often lead to an inflationary bubble, which could collapse if people began demanding hard money, causing the demand for paper notes to fall to zero. The printing of paper money was also associated with wars, and financing of wars, and therefore regarded as part of maintaining a . For these reasons, paper currency was held in suspicion and hostility in Europe and America. It was also addictive since the speculative profits of trade and capital creation were quite large. Major nations established mints to print money and mint coins, and branches of their treasury to collect taxes and hold gold and silver stock.

At this time both silver and gold were considered , and accepted by governments for taxes. However, the instability in the ratio between the two grew over the 19th century, with the increase both in the supply of these metals, particularly silver, and of trade. This is called and the attempt to create a bimetallic standard where both gold and silver backed currency remained in circulation occupied the efforts of inflationists. Governments at this point could use currency as an instrument of policy, printing paper currency such as the United States greenback, to pay for military expenditures. They could also set the terms at which they would redeem notes for specie, by limiting the amount of purchase, or the minimum amount that could be redeemed.

By 1900, most of the industrializing nations were on some form of a gold standard, with paper notes and silver coins constituting the circulating medium. Private banks and governments across the world followed Gresham's law: keeping gold and silver paid but paying out in notes. This did not happen all around the world at the same time, but occurred sporadically, generally in times of war or financial crisis, beginning in the early part of the 20th century and continuing across the world until the late 20th century, when the regime of floating fiat currencies came into force. One of the last countries to break away from the was the United States in 1971.

No country anywhere in the world today has an enforceable gold standard or currency system.


Commercial bank
Commercial bank money or are claims against financial institutions that can be used for the purchase of goods and services. A demand deposit account is an account from which funds can be withdrawn at any time by check or withdrawal without giving the bank or financial institution any prior notice. Banks have the legal obligation to return funds held in demand deposits immediately upon demand (or 'at call'). Demand deposit withdrawals can be performed in person, via checks or bank drafts, using automatic teller machines (ATMs), or through .
(2025). 9780130630858, Pearson Prentice Hall. .

Commercial bank money is created by commercial banks whose (held as cash and other highly liquid assets) typically constitute only a fraction of their , while the banks maintain an obligation to redeem all these deposits upon demand - a practise known as fractional-reserve banking. Commercial bank money differs from commodity and fiat money in two ways: firstly it is non-physical, as its existence is only reflected in the account ledgers of banks and other financial institutions, and secondly, there is some element of risk that the claim will not be fulfilled if the financial institution becomes insolvent.

The theory presents the process of creating commercial bank money as a multiple (greater than 1) of the amount of created by the country's , the multiple itself being a function of the of banks imposed by financial regulators (e.g., potential reserve requirements) beside the business policies of and the preferences of - factors which the central bank can influence, but not control completely.

(2025). 9781349951215, Palgrave Macmillan UK.
Contemporary central banks generally do not control the creation of money, nor do they try to, though their interest rate-setting monetary policies naturally affect the amount of loans and deposits that commercial banks create.


Digital or electronic
The development of computer technology in the second part of the twentieth century allowed money to be represented digitally. By 1990, in the United States all money transferred between its central bank and commercial banks was in electronic form. By the 2000s most money existed as in bank databases. In 2012, by number of transaction, 20 to 58 percent of transactions were electronic (dependent on country).

Anonymous digital currencies were developed in the early 2000s. Early examples include , , , and . Not much innovation occurred until the conception of in 2008, which introduced the concept of a decentralised currency that requires no trusted third party.


Monetary policy
When gold and silver were used as money, the money supply could grow only if the supply of these metals was increased by mining. This rate of increase would accelerate during periods of and discoveries, such as when Columbus traveled to the and brought back gold and silver to Spain, or when gold was discovered in California in 1848. This caused inflation, as the value of gold went down. However, if the rate of could not keep up with the growth of the economy, gold became relatively more valuable, and prices (denominated in gold) would drop, causing deflation. Deflation was the more typical situation for over a century when gold and paper money backed by gold were used as money in the 18th and 19th centuries.

Modern-day monetary systems are based on fiat money and are no longer tied to the value of gold. The amount of money in the economy is influenced by , which is the process by which a influences the economy to achieve specific goals. Often, the goal of monetary policy is to maintain low and stable , directly via an inflation targeting strategy, or indirectly via a fixed exchange rate system against a major currency with a stable inflation rate.

(2023). 9798400235269, International Monetary Fund. .
In some cases, the central bank may pursue various supplementary goals. For example, it is clearly stated in the Federal Reserve Act that the Board of Governors and the Federal Open Market Committee should seek "to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates."The Federal Reserve. 'Monetary Policy and the Economy". () Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, (2005-07-05). Retrieved 2007-05-15.

A failed monetary policy can have significant detrimental effects on an economy and the society that depends on it. These include , , , high unemployment, shortages of imported goods, inability to export goods, and even total monetary collapse and the adoption of a much less efficient barter economy. This happened in Russia, for instance, after the fall of the Soviet Union.

Monetary policy strategies have changed over time. Some of the tools used to conduct contemporary monetary policy include:

  • changing the at which the central bank loans money to (or borrows money from) the commercial banks
  • open market operations including currency purchases or sales
  • , i.e. publishing forecasts to communicate the likely future course of monetary policy
  • raising or lowering bank reserve requirements

In the U.S., the is responsible for conducting monetary policy, while in the the respective institution is the European Central Bank. Other central banks with a significant impact on global finances are the Bank of Japan, People's Bank of China and the Bank of England.

During the 1970s and 1980s monetary policy in several countries was influenced by an known as monetarism. argued that management of the should be the primary means of regulating economic activity. The stability of the demand for money prior to the 1980s was a key finding of and

(1971). 9780691003542, Princeton University Press.
supported by the work of ,
(1997). 9781858985961, Edward Elgar Publishing. .
and many others. It turned out, however, that maintaining a monetary policy strategy of targeting the money supply did not work very well: The relation between money growth and inflation was not as tight as expected by monetarist theory, and the short-run relation between the money supply and the interest rate, which is the chief instrument through which the central bank can influence output and inflation, was unreliable. Both problems were due to unpredictable shifts in the demand for money. Consequently, starting in the early 1990s a fundamental reorientation took place in most major central banks, starting to target inflation directly instead of the money supply and using the interest rate as their main instrument.
(2025). 9780134897899, Pearson.


Locality
The definition of money says it is money only "in a particular country or socio-economic context". In general, communities only use a single measure of value, which can be identified in the prices of goods listed for sale. There might be multiple media of exchange, which can be observed by what is given to purchase goods ("medium of exchange"), etc. In most countries, the government acts to encourage a particular forms of money, such as requiring it for taxes and punishing .

Some places do maintain two or more currencies, particularly in border towns or high-travel areas. Shops in these locations might list prices and accept payment in multiple currencies. Otherwise, foreign currency is treated as a in the local market. Foreign currency is commonly bought or sold on foreign exchange markets by travelers and traders.

Communities can change the money they use, which is known as currency substitution. This can happen intentionally, when a government issues a new currency. For example, when Brazil moved from the Brazilian cruzeiro to the . It can also happen spontaneously, when the people refuse to accept a currency experiencing (even if its use is encouraged by the government).

The money used by a community can change on a smaller scale. This can come through innovation, such as the adoption of . Gresham's law says that "bad money drives out good". That is, when buying a good, a person is more likely to pass on less-desirable items that qualify as "money" and hold on to more valuable ones. For example, coins with less silver in them (but which are still valid coins) are more likely to circulate in the community. This may effectively change the money used by a community.

The money used by a community does not have to be a currency issued by a government. A famous example of community adopting a new form of money is prisoners-of-war using cigarettes to trade.


Financial crimes

Counterfeiting
Counterfeit money is imitation currency produced without the legal sanction of the state or government. Producing or using counterfeit money is a form of fraud or forgery. Counterfeiting is almost as old as money itself. Plated copies (known as Fourrées) have been found of Lydian coins which are thought to be among the first western coins. Historically, objects that were difficult to counterfeit (e.g. shells, rare stones, precious metals) were often chosen as money. Before the introduction of , the most prevalent method of counterfeiting involved mixing base metals with pure gold or silver. A form of counterfeiting is the production of documents by legitimate printers in response to fraudulent instructions. During World War II, the forged British pounds and American dollars. Today some of the finest counterfeit banknotes are called because of their high quality and likeness to the real U.S. dollar. There has been significant counterfeiting of banknotes and coins since the launch of the currency in 2002, but considerably less than for the U.S. dollar.


Money laundering
Money laundering is the process in which the proceeds of crime are transformed into ostensibly legitimate money or other assets. However, in several legal and regulatory systems the term money laundering has become with other forms of financial crime, and sometimes used more generally to include misuse of the financial system (involving things such as securities, , credit cards, and traditional currency), including terrorism financing, , and evading of international sanctions.


See also


Notes

Further reading
  • Brzezinski, Adam; Palma, Nuno; Velde, François R. (2024). "". Annual Review of Economics.
  • Chown, John F. A History of Money: from AD 800 (Psychology Press, 1994).
  • Davies, Glyn, and Duncan Connors. A History of Money (4th ed. U of Wales Press, 2016) excerpt .
  • . The Ascent of Money: A Financial History of the World (2009) excerpt
  • (February 2015). "What Is Money and How Is It Created?" argues, "Banks create money by issuing a loan to a borrower; they record the loan as an asset, and the money they deposit in the borrower's account as a liability. This, in one way, is no different to the way the Federal Reserve creates money ... money is simply a third party's promise to pay which we accept as full payment in exchange for goods. The two main third parties whose promises we accept are the government and the banks ... money ... is not backed by anything physical, and instead relies on trust. Of course, that trust can be abused ... we continue to ignore the main game: what the banks do (for good and for ill) that really drives the economy." Forbes
  • Kuroda, Akinobu. A Global History of Money (Routledge, 2020). excerpt
  • , "The Invention of Money: How the heresies of two bankers became the basis of our modern economy", The New Yorker, 5 & 12 August 2019, pp. 28–31.
  • . An Outline of the Origins of Money (University of Chicago Press, 2024). Translated and annotated, with an introduction by Enrique Martino and Mario Schmidt. Foreword by Michael Hudson. PDF
  • Weatherford, Jack. The history of money (2009). by a cultural anthropologist. excerpt


External links
  • "Money", BBC Radio 4 discussion with Niall Ferguson, Richard J. Evans and Jane Humphries ( In Our Time, Mar. 1, 2001)

Page 1 of 1
1
Page 1 of 1
1

Account

Social:
Pages:  ..   .. 
Items:  .. 

Navigation

General: Atom Feed Atom Feed  .. 
Help:  ..   .. 
Category:  ..   .. 
Media:  ..   .. 
Posts:  ..   ..   .. 

Statistics

Page:  .. 
Summary:  .. 
1 Tags
10/10 Page Rank
5 Page Refs
3s Time