In sociology and in economics, the term conspicuous consumption describes and explains the consumer practice of buying and using goods of a higher quality, price, or in greater quantity than practical.Phillips, Ronnie J. 2014 April 22. " Conspicuous consumption." Encyclopedia Britannica. In 1899, the sociologist Thorstein Veblen coined the term conspicuous consumption to explain the spending of money on and the acquiring of Luxury good (goods and services) specifically as a public display of economic power—the income and the accumulated wealth—of the buyer. To the conspicuous consumer, the public display of discretionary income is an economic means of either attaining or maintaining a given social status. The New Fontana Dictionary of Modern Thought, Third Edition, Alan Bullock, Stephen Trombley, Eds., 1993, p. 162.
The development of Veblen's sociology of conspicuous consumption also identified and described other economic behaviours such as invidious consumption, which is the ostentatious consumption of goods, an action meant to provoke the envy of other people; and conspicuous compassion, the ostentatious use of charity meant to enhance the reputation and social prestige of the donor;
In the 1920s, economists such as Paul Nystrom proposed that changes in lifestyle as result of the industrial age led to massive expansion of the "pecuniary emulation." That conspicuous consumption had induced in the mass of society a "philosophy of futility" that would increase the consumption of goods and services as a social fashion; consumption for the sake of consumption.
In 1949, James Duesenberry proposed the "demonstration effect" and the "bandwagon effect", whereby a person's conspicuous consumption psychologically depends upon the actual level of spending, but also depends upon the degree of his or her spending, when compared with and to the spending of other people. That the conspicuous consumer is motivated by the importance, to him or to her, of the opinion of the social and economic reference groups for whom he or she are performed the conspicuous consumption.
In (1996), Thomas J. Stanley and William D. Danko reported conspicuous frugality, another variation of Veblen's social-class relation to conspicuous consumption. That Americans with a net worth of more than a million dollars usually avoid conspicuous consumption, and tend to practise frugality, such as paying cash for a used car rather using credit, in order to avoid material depreciation and paying interest upon a car loan.
Moreover, D. Hebdige, in Hiding in the Light (1994), proposes that conspicuous consumption is a form of displaying a personal identity,Hebdige, D. (1994) Hiding in the Light. London: Routledge.Wilson, E. (ed.) Chic Thrills. A Fashion Reader. London: HarperCollins and a consequent function of advertising, as proposed in Ads, Fads, and Consumer Culture (2000), by A. A. Berger.Berger, A. A. (2000) Ads, Fads, and Consumer Culture. Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield. Each variant interpretation and complementary explanation is derived from Veblen's original sociologic proposition in The Theory of the Leisure Class: that conspicuous consumption is a psychological end in itself, from which the practitioner (man, woman, family) derived the honour of superior social status.
Conspicuous compassion, the practice of publicly donating large sums of money to charity to enhance the Reputation of the donor, is sometimes described as a type of conspicuous consumption. This behaviour has long been recognised and sometimes attacked—for example, the New Testament story Lesson of the widow's mite criticises wealthy people who make large donations ostentatiously, while praising poorer people who make small but comparatively more difficult donations in private.
Possible motivations for conspicuous consumption include:
Oversized houses facilitated other forms of conspicuous consumption, such as an oversized garage for the family's oversized motor vehicles or buying more clothing to fill larger clothes closets. Conspicuous consumption becomes a self-generating cycle of spending money for the sake of social prestige. Analogous to the consumer trend for oversized houses is the trend towards buying oversized , specifically the off-road sport utility vehicle type (cf. station wagon/estate car), as a form of psychologically comforting conspicuous consumption, because such large vehicles usually are bought by city-dwellers, an urban nuclear family.
Do I enjoy a decent bath because I know that John Smith cannot afford one—or because I delight in being clean? Do I admire Beethoven's Fifth Symphony because it is incomprehensible to Congressmen and Methodists—or because I genuinely love music? Do I prefer terrapin à la Maryland to fried liver because plowhands must put up with the liver—or because the terrapin is intrinsically a more charming dose? Do I prefer kissing a pretty girl to kissing a charwoman, because even a janitor may kiss a charwoman—or because the pretty girl looks better, smells better, and kisses better?
The findings that Banuri and Nguyen reported indicate that the cyclical effect of borrowing money for conspicuous consumption leads to and perpetuates economic inequality. That poor people imitate, try to match, and emulate the consumption patterns of rich people in order to increase their social status, and perhaps rise in society. That such socio-economic behaviours, facilitated by easy access to credit, generate macroeconomic volatility and support Veblen's concept of pecuniary emulation used to finance a person's social standing.
Other research supports these and similar results. For example income inequality has been found to be associated with reduced savings rates.Michael Kumhof, Romain Rancière, and Pablo Winant, "Inequality, Leverage, and Crises"
One complication found in the macro literature is that the link between inequality and savings may depend on context, in particular on the degree of financialisation. When the degree of financialisation is high, inequality tends to reduce the national savings rate as the emulation effect is more powerful when finance is readily available, but the opposite effect may occur when financialisation is low as the emulation effect is weak, and the rich tend to save at a higher rate than the poor.Peter Bofinger and Philipp Scheuermeyer, "Income Distribution and Aggregate Saving: A Non-Monotonic Relationship"
In the case where inequality lowers savings, and increases leverage and a tendency to run large current account imbalances via the expenditure cascade mechanism, this has been associated with more frequent and/or severe economic crisis.Cristiano Perugini, Jens Hölscher, and Simon Collie, "Inequality, Credit and Financial Crises"
In place of luxury taxes, economist Robert H. Frank proposed the application of a progressive consumption tax; in a 1998 New York Times article, John Tierney said that as a remedy for the social and psychological malaise that is conspicuous consumption, the personal income tax should be replaced with a progressive tax upon the yearly sum of discretionary income spent on the conspicuous consumption of goods and services. Another option is the redistribution of wealth, either by means of an incomes policy – for example the conscious efforts to promote wage compression under variants of social corporatism such as the Rehn–Meidner model and/or by some mix of progressive taxation and transfer policies, and provision of public goods. When individuals are concerned with their relative income or consumption in comparison to their peers, the optimal degree of public good provision and of progression of the tax system is raised. Because the activity of conspicuous consumption, itself, is a form of superior good, diminishing the income inequality of the income distribution by way of an egalitarian policy reduces the conspicuous consumption of positional goods and services. In Wealth and Welfare (1912), the economist A. C. Pigou said that the redistribution of wealth might lead to great gains in social welfare:
The economic case for the taxation of positional, luxury goods has a long history; in the mid-19th century, in Principles of Political Economy with some of their Applications to Social Philosophy (1848), John Stuart Mill said:
In the case where conspicuous consumption mediates a link between inequality and unsustainable borrowing, one suggested policy response is tighter financial regulation.Joshua Aizenman, Menzie D. Chinn, and Hiro Ito, "Financial Spillovers and Macroprudential Policies"
"Conspicuous non-consumption" is a phrase used to describe a conscious choice to opt out of consumption with the intention of sending deliberate social signals.
/ref>Michael Kumhof et al., "Income Inequality and Current Account Imbalances” (IMF, 2012), http://ideas.repec.org/p/imf/imfwpa/12-8.html Christopher Brown, Inequality, Consumer Credit and the Savings Puzzle (Cheltnham: Edward Elgar, 2008) One hypothesized mechanism for this relationship is 'expenditure cascades'Robert H. Frank, Adam Seth Levine, and Oege Dijk, "Expenditure Cascades"
/ref> whereby consumption norms are set by the relatively wealthy, who then have more income and consumption relative to others as inequality rises. This emulation of the consumption norms of relatively wealthy peers is supported by a large literature.Moritz Drechsel-Grau and Kai D. Schmid, "Consumption–Savings Decisions under Upward-Looking Comparisons"
/ref>Francisco Alvarez-Cuadrado, Jose Maria Casado, and Jose Maria Labeaga, "Envy and Habits: Panel Data Estimates of Interdependent Preferences"
/ref>Marianne Bertrand and Adair Morse, "Trickle-Down Consumption", Working Paper (National Bureau of Economic Research, March 2013), http://www.nber.org/papers/w18883Peter Kuhn et al., "The Effects of Lottery Prizes on Winners and Their Neighbors: Evidence from the Dutch Postcode Lottery"
/ref>Marianne Bertrand and Adair Morse, "Consumption Contagion: Does the Consumption of the Rich Drive the Consumption of the Less Rich?.", 2011, faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/morse/research/papers/NBER_reporter_summaryAug2011.pdfRachel E. Dwyer, "The McMansionization of America? Income Stratification and the Standard of Living in Housing, 1960-2000"
10.1016/j.rssm.2009.09.003Bill Dupor and Wen-Fang Liu, "Jealousy and Equilibrium Overconsumption", American Economic Review 93, no. 1 (2003): 423–28H. L. Cole, G. J. Mailath, and A. Postlewaite, "Social Norms, Savings Behavior, and Growth", Journal of Political Economy 100, no. 6 (1992): 1092–1127.
/ref> The effect of inequality on savings is also found to be positive in Asia, where financialization is lower.inhua Gu et al., "Inequality and Saving: Further Evidence from Integrated Economies"
/ref>Baomin Dong, and Bihong Huang, "Inequality, Saving and Global Imbalances: A New Theory with Evidence from OECD and Asian Countries"
/ref> The relationship is also found to depend on economic policy and institutions. For example inequality appears to lower savings in Market Economy but to rather reduce aggregate demand in Planned Economy.Jan Behringer and Till van Treeck, "Varieties of Capitalism and Growth Regimes: The Role of Income Distribution"
/ref>
/ref> Malinen, "Does Income Inequality Contribute to Credit Cycles?"
/ref> J. Michell, "Income Distribution and the Financial and Economic Crisis", in The Demise of Finance-Dominated Capitalism: Explaining the Financial and Economic Crises, ed. Eckhard Hein, Daniel Detzer, and Nina Dodig (Cheltenham, UK ; Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar Pub, 2015)Michael Kumhof, Romain Rancière, and Pablo Winant, "Inequality, Leverage, and Crises"
/ref>Michael Kumhof, Romain Ranciere, and Pablo Winant, "Inequality, Leverage and Crises; The Case of Endogenous Default"
Fadhel Kaboub, Zdravka Todorova, and Luisa Fernandez, "Inequality-Led Financial Instability", International Journal of Political Economy 39, no. 1 (Spring 2010): 3–27Richard Breen and Cecilia García-Peñalosa, "Income Inequality and Macroeconomic Volatility: An Empirical Investigation", Review of Development Economics 9, no. 3 (2005): 380–98Andrew G. Berg and Jonathan D. Ostry, "Inequality and Unsustainable Growth: Two Sides of the Same Coin?", IMF Staff Discussion Notes (IMF, April 8, 2011), http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2011/sdn1108.pdf.
Solutions
Joseph E Stiglitz, "New Theoretical Perspectives on the Distribution of Income and Wealth among Individuals: Part IV: Land and Credit"
/ref>
See also
Further reading
target="_blank" rel="nofollow"> The Good Life: An International Perspective, a short article by Amitai Etzioni
|
|